All Working Papers
with Maarten Meeuwis, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revise and Resubmit at the American Economic Review. Updated December 2023
We show that time variation in risk premia leads to time-varying idiosyncratic income risk for workers. Using US administrative data on worker earnings, we show that increases in risk premia lead to lower earnings for low-wage workers; these declines are primarily driven by job separations. By contrast, productivity shocks affect the earnings mainly of highly paid workers. We build an equilibrium model of labor market search that quantitatively replicates these facts. The model generates endogenous time-varying income risk in response to changes in risk premia and matches several stylized features of the data regarding unemployment and income risk over the business cycle.
with Carter Braxton, Kyle Herkenhoff, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revised and resubmitted (2nd round) to the American Economic Review. Last updated in October 2024
For whom has earnings risk changed, and why? We answer these questions by combining the Kalman filter and EM-algorithm to estimate persistent and temporary earnings for every individual at every point in time. We apply our method to administrative earnings linked with survey data. We show that since the 1980s, persistent earnings risk rose by 12.5% for both employed and unemployed workers and the scarring effects of unemployment doubled. At the same time, temporary earnings risk declined. Using education and occupation codes, we show that rising persistent earnings risk is concentrated among high-skill workers and related to technology adoption.
with Taha Choukhmane, Jorge Colmenares, Cormac O'Dea, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revise and Resubmit at the American Economic Review. Updated August 2024
U.S. employers and the federal government devote over 1.5% of GDP annually toward promoting defined contribution (DC) retirement saving. Using a new employer-employee linked dataset covering millions of Americans, we show that this system of saving incentives benefits White workers and those with richer parents more than their similar-income coworkers who are Black or Hispanic or from lower-income families. Breaking the link between contribution choices and saving subsidies—through revenue- neutral reforms—can close the gaps in DC wealth between Black and White workers, between Hispanic and White workers, and between those with the richest and those with the poorest parents by close to a third.
with Leonid Kogan, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Bryan Seegmiller. Updated July 2024
We develop measures of labor-saving and labor-augmenting technology exposure using textual analysis of patents and job tasks. Using US administrative data, we show that exposure to labor-saving technologies negatively affects the earnings of exposed workers. This negative effect is pervasive across both blue- and white-collar workers and across workers of different ages or earnings relative to their peers. In contrast, labor-augmenting technologies have a heterogeneous impact on exposed workers. While the wage bill paid to affected groups rises, this increase is driven primarily by an increase in employment, while earnings rise for new entrants but decline for incumbent workers. This decline is primarily present among white-collar, older, and higher-paid workers, highlighting the importance of vintage-specific human capital. Last, we find positive spillovers of both types of innovation at the industry level, benefiting other workers in the same industry who are not directly exposed to these innovations.
Job Market Paper, Revise and Resubmit at the Journal of Financial Economics. Winner of 2015 AQR Top Finance Graduate Award and 2015 Cubist Systematic Strategies Ph.D. Candidate Award for Outstanding Research
Administrative earnings data reveal that households are exposed to large, countercyclical idiosyncratic tail risks in labor earnings. I illustrate how these risks affect asset prices within an asset pricing framework with recursive preferences, heterogeneous agents and incomplete markets. Quantitatively, a model in which agents face a time-varying probability of experiencing a rare, idiosyncratic disaster, with parameters disciplined by data, matches the level and dynamics of the equity premium. Stock returns are highly informative about labor market event risk, and, consistent with model predictions, initial claims for unemployment, a proxy for labor market uncertainty, is a highly robust predictor of returns.
with Leonid Kogan, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Jae Song.
Using administrative data from the United States, we document novel stylized facts regarding technological innovation and the riskiness of labor income. Higher rates of industry innovation are associated with significant increases in labor earnings for top workers. Decomposing this result, we find that own firm innovation is associated with a modest increase in the mean, but also variance, of worker earnings growth. Innovation by competing firms is related to lower, and more negatively skewed, future earnings. We construct a structural model featuring creative destruction and displacement of human capital that replicates these patterns. In the model, higher rates of innovation by competing firms increase the likelihood that both the worker and the incumbent producer are displaced. By contrast, a higher rate of innovation by the worker's own firm increases profits, but is a mixed blessing for workers, as it increases odds that the skilled worker is no longer a good match to the new technology. Estimating the parameters of the model using indirect inference, we find significant welfare losses and hedging demand against innovation shocks. Consistent with our model, we find that these left tail effects are more pronounced for process improvements, novel innovations, and are concentrated in movers rather than continuing workers.
with Sung Je Byun and Johnathan Loudis.
In addition to a priced, dominant market factor (DMF), the value-weighted market stock return contains an “idiosyncratic financial factor” (IFF) related to overweighting of large-cap stocks. The IFF carries no risk premium, is unrelated to macroeconomic factors and returns in other markets, and significantly impacts systematic risk estimates. Size factors separate exposures to the DMF from the IFF. Consistent with a model with nontraded assets, using the DMF as an alternative market factor resolves the size anomaly and obviates the need for size factors in multifactor models. Finally, the DMF features a stronger intertemporal risk-return tradeoff.
with Janet Gao, Shan Ge, and Cristina Tello-Trillo
Employer-sponsored health insurance is a significant component of labor costs. We examine the causal effect of health insurance premiums on firms’ employment and employment outcomes of low- versus high-income workers. To address endogeneity concerns, we instrument for insurance premiums using idiosyncratic variation in insurers’ recent losses, which is plausibly exogenous to their customers who are employers. Using Census microdata, we show that following an exogenous increase in premiums, firms reduce employment. Lower-income workers become more likely to be separated from their jobs, become unemployed, experience a large earning reduction upon job separation, and be part-time (ineligible for health insurance benefits).
with Fiona Greig, Anna Madamba, Guillermo Carranza, Cormac O'Dea, Taha Choukhmane, May 2024
We propose criteria that employers can use to evaluate their match formula: equity, efficiency, and cost. Recognizing that plan sponsors have different objectives and constraints, we offer the criteria to help sponsors make the tradeoffs in plan design explicit and help them meet their goals.
In two-thirds of plans, employer contributions exacerbate pay inequity. Employer contributions are highly concentrated, with 44% of dollars accruing to the top 20% of earners. Many common formulas, including safe harbor designs, disproportionately benefit higher-income employees. An employer match is efficient if it encourages workers to save more. Employee saving rates vary little across plans with different levels of employer matches. The majority (59%) of employer contributions accrue to the 41 % of employees who save more than the match cap, suggesting they would have saved just as much without the match.
Employer contribution costs vary widely. No single formula is a clear winner in terms of efficiency, but dollar caps are more equitable and contain costs. Nonelective contributions that decouple employer contributions from employee choices can also be designed to achieve equity objectives.
Policymakers could do more to promote equity. Adopting additional safe harbor standards with equity considerations could nudge plans toward more equitable designs.
with Adam Bee, Joshua Mitchell, Nikolas Mittag, Jonathan Rothbaum, Carl Sanders, and Matthew Unrath.
Accurately measuring household income and poverty is essential to understanding the nation’s overall economic wellbeing. Many studies show that measurement error stemming from unit nonresponse, item nonresponse and misreporting biases key official statistics such as mean or median income and the official poverty rate. The direction of bias differs between these sources of measurement error. Since these error components are typically studied in isolation, their overall impact on the accuracy of survey estimates remains unclear. This paper summarizes the National Experimental Wellbeing Statistics (NEWS) Project, which integrates this research and address each of these sources of bias simultaneously in order to produce more accurate estimates of household income and poverty. The NEWS project makes three unique contributions. First, we address as many sources of measurement error as we can simultaneously – including unit and item nonresponse and underreporting in surveys as well as the various challenges in administrative data such as measurement error, conceptual misalignment, and incomplete coverage. Second, we bring together all of the available survey and administrative data, which allows to address many of the shortcomings of individual data sources. Third, we propose a model to combine survey and administrative earnings data given measurement error in both sources, replacing ad hoc assumptions that have been used in prior work.
with Yinchu Zhu, Walter P. Heller Memorial Award Winner. New draft coming soon!
We propose a simple alternative to linear-in-parameters quantile regressions for the modeling of conditional distributions. We parameterize the conditional quantile function in terms of a single "location" quantile (usually the median), to which we add or subtract sums of exponentially affine functions (quantile spacings) to obtain a finite number of other quantiles. Our generalized location-scale specification preserves the computational tractability of standard linear quantile regression, is not subject to the quantile crossing problem, and the separability restriction we impose on scale can be motivated by the non-parametric generalization of differences-in-differences of Athey and Imbens (2006). Thus, under some assumptions, an application of our method extends nonlinear differences-in- differences to allow for many, potentially continuous covariates. We illustrate the utility of the method by considering impacts of mass layoffs on the distribution of displaced workers’ earnings using employer-employee matched data from the US. We find that average effects, which are in line with established literature, are driven by a substantial fattening of the left tail, a phenomenon which is further exacerbated during macroeconomic downturns, suggesting that the welfare costs of cyclical variation in income losses from job displacement are even higher than considering average effects alone.
All Working Papers
with Maarten Meeuwis, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revise and Resubmit at the American Economic Review. Updated December 2023
We show that time variation in risk premia leads to time-varying idiosyncratic income risk for workers. Using US administrative data on worker earnings, we show that increases in risk premia lead to lower earnings for low-wage workers; these declines are primarily driven by job separations. By contrast, productivity shocks affect the earnings mainly of highly paid workers. We build an equilibrium model of labor market search that quantitatively replicates these facts. The model generates endogenous time-varying income risk in response to changes in risk premia and matches several stylized features of the data regarding unemployment and income risk over the business cycle.
with Carter Braxton, Kyle Herkenhoff, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revised and resubmitted (2nd round) to the American Economic Review. Last updated in October 2024
For whom has earnings risk changed, and why? We answer these questions by combining the Kalman filter and EM-algorithm to estimate persistent and temporary earnings for every individual at every point in time. We apply our method to administrative earnings linked with survey data. We show that since the 1980s, persistent earnings risk rose by 12.5% for both employed and unemployed workers and the scarring effects of unemployment doubled. At the same time, temporary earnings risk declined. Using education and occupation codes, we show that rising persistent earnings risk is concentrated among high-skill workers and related to technology adoption.
with Taha Choukhmane, Jorge Colmenares, Cormac O'Dea, and Jonathan Rothbaum. Revise and Resubmit at the American Economic Review. Updated August 2024
U.S. employers and the federal government devote over 1.5% of GDP annually toward promoting defined contribution (DC) retirement saving. Using a new employer-employee linked dataset covering millions of Americans, we show that this system of saving incentives benefits White workers and those with richer parents more than their similar-income coworkers who are Black or Hispanic or from lower-income families. Breaking the link between contribution choices and saving subsidies—through revenue- neutral reforms—can close the gaps in DC wealth between Black and White workers, between Hispanic and White workers, and between those with the richest and those with the poorest parents by close to a third.
with Leonid Kogan, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Bryan Seegmiller. Updated July 2024
We develop measures of labor-saving and labor-augmenting technology exposure using textual analysis of patents and job tasks. Using US administrative data, we show that exposure to labor-saving technologies negatively affects the earnings of exposed workers. This negative effect is pervasive across both blue- and white-collar workers and across workers of different ages or earnings relative to their peers. In contrast, labor-augmenting technologies have a heterogeneous impact on exposed workers. While the wage bill paid to affected groups rises, this increase is driven primarily by an increase in employment, while earnings rise for new entrants but decline for incumbent workers. This decline is primarily present among white-collar, older, and higher-paid workers, highlighting the importance of vintage-specific human capital. Last, we find positive spillovers of both types of innovation at the industry level, benefiting other workers in the same industry who are not directly exposed to these innovations.
Job Market Paper, Revise and Resubmit at the Journal of Financial Economics. Winner of 2015 AQR Top Finance Graduate Award and 2015 Cubist Systematic Strategies Ph.D. Candidate Award for Outstanding Research
Administrative earnings data reveal that households are exposed to large, countercyclical idiosyncratic tail risks in labor earnings. I illustrate how these risks affect asset prices within an asset pricing framework with recursive preferences, heterogeneous agents and incomplete markets. Quantitatively, a model in which agents face a time-varying probability of experiencing a rare, idiosyncratic disaster, with parameters disciplined by data, matches the level and dynamics of the equity premium. Stock returns are highly informative about labor market event risk, and, consistent with model predictions, initial claims for unemployment, a proxy for labor market uncertainty, is a highly robust predictor of returns.
with Leonid Kogan, Dimitris Papanikolaou, and Jae Song.
Using administrative data from the United States, we document novel stylized facts regarding technological innovation and the riskiness of labor income. Higher rates of industry innovation are associated with significant increases in labor earnings for top workers. Decomposing this result, we find that own firm innovation is associated with a modest increase in the mean, but also variance, of worker earnings growth. Innovation by competing firms is related to lower, and more negatively skewed, future earnings. We construct a structural model featuring creative destruction and displacement of human capital that replicates these patterns. In the model, higher rates of innovation by competing firms increase the likelihood that both the worker and the incumbent producer are displaced. By contrast, a higher rate of innovation by the worker's own firm increases profits, but is a mixed blessing for workers, as it increases odds that the skilled worker is no longer a good match to the new technology. Estimating the parameters of the model using indirect inference, we find significant welfare losses and hedging demand against innovation shocks. Consistent with our model, we find that these left tail effects are more pronounced for process improvements, novel innovations, and are concentrated in movers rather than continuing workers.
with Sung Je Byun and Johnathan Loudis.
In addition to a priced, dominant market factor (DMF), the value-weighted market stock return contains an “idiosyncratic financial factor” (IFF) related to overweighting of large-cap stocks. The IFF carries no risk premium, is unrelated to macroeconomic factors and returns in other markets, and significantly impacts systematic risk estimates. Size factors separate exposures to the DMF from the IFF. Consistent with a model with nontraded assets, using the DMF as an alternative market factor resolves the size anomaly and obviates the need for size factors in multifactor models. Finally, the DMF features a stronger intertemporal risk-return tradeoff.
with Janet Gao, Shan Ge, and Cristina Tello-Trillo
Employer-sponsored health insurance is a significant component of labor costs. We examine the causal effect of health insurance premiums on firms’ employment and employment outcomes of low- versus high-income workers. To address endogeneity concerns, we instrument for insurance premiums using idiosyncratic variation in insurers’ recent losses, which is plausibly exogenous to their customers who are employers. Using Census microdata, we show that following an exogenous increase in premiums, firms reduce employment. Lower-income workers become more likely to be separated from their jobs, become unemployed, experience a large earning reduction upon job separation, and be part-time (ineligible for health insurance benefits).
with Fiona Greig, Anna Madamba, Guillermo Carranza, Cormac O'Dea, Taha Choukhmane, May 2024
We propose criteria that employers can use to evaluate their match formula: equity, efficiency, and cost. Recognizing that plan sponsors have different objectives and constraints, we offer the criteria to help sponsors make the tradeoffs in plan design explicit and help them meet their goals.
In two-thirds of plans, employer contributions exacerbate pay inequity. Employer contributions are highly concentrated, with 44% of dollars accruing to the top 20% of earners. Many common formulas, including safe harbor designs, disproportionately benefit higher-income employees. An employer match is efficient if it encourages workers to save more. Employee saving rates vary little across plans with different levels of employer matches. The majority (59%) of employer contributions accrue to the 41 % of employees who save more than the match cap, suggesting they would have saved just as much without the match.
Employer contribution costs vary widely. No single formula is a clear winner in terms of efficiency, but dollar caps are more equitable and contain costs. Nonelective contributions that decouple employer contributions from employee choices can also be designed to achieve equity objectives.
Policymakers could do more to promote equity. Adopting additional safe harbor standards with equity considerations could nudge plans toward more equitable designs.
with Adam Bee, Joshua Mitchell, Nikolas Mittag, Jonathan Rothbaum, Carl Sanders, and Matthew Unrath.
Accurately measuring household income and poverty is essential to understanding the nation’s overall economic wellbeing. Many studies show that measurement error stemming from unit nonresponse, item nonresponse and misreporting biases key official statistics such as mean or median income and the official poverty rate. The direction of bias differs between these sources of measurement error. Since these error components are typically studied in isolation, their overall impact on the accuracy of survey estimates remains unclear. This paper summarizes the National Experimental Wellbeing Statistics (NEWS) Project, which integrates this research and address each of these sources of bias simultaneously in order to produce more accurate estimates of household income and poverty. The NEWS project makes three unique contributions. First, we address as many sources of measurement error as we can simultaneously – including unit and item nonresponse and underreporting in surveys as well as the various challenges in administrative data such as measurement error, conceptual misalignment, and incomplete coverage. Second, we bring together all of the available survey and administrative data, which allows to address many of the shortcomings of individual data sources. Third, we propose a model to combine survey and administrative earnings data given measurement error in both sources, replacing ad hoc assumptions that have been used in prior work.
with Yinchu Zhu, Walter P. Heller Memorial Award Winner. New draft coming soon!
We propose a simple alternative to linear-in-parameters quantile regressions for the modeling of conditional distributions. We parameterize the conditional quantile function in terms of a single "location" quantile (usually the median), to which we add or subtract sums of exponentially affine functions (quantile spacings) to obtain a finite number of other quantiles. Our generalized location-scale specification preserves the computational tractability of standard linear quantile regression, is not subject to the quantile crossing problem, and the separability restriction we impose on scale can be motivated by the non-parametric generalization of differences-in-differences of Athey and Imbens (2006). Thus, under some assumptions, an application of our method extends nonlinear differences-in- differences to allow for many, potentially continuous covariates. We illustrate the utility of the method by considering impacts of mass layoffs on the distribution of displaced workers’ earnings using employer-employee matched data from the US. We find that average effects, which are in line with established literature, are driven by a substantial fattening of the left tail, a phenomenon which is further exacerbated during macroeconomic downturns, suggesting that the welfare costs of cyclical variation in income losses from job displacement are even higher than considering average effects alone.
All Publications
with Klakow Akepanidtaworn, Rick Di Mascio, and Alex Imas. Journal of Finance, August 2023
Are market experts prone to heuristics, and if so, do they transfer across closely related domains---buying and selling? We investigate this question using a unique dataset of institutional investors with portfolios averaging $573 million. A striking finding emerges: while there is clear evidence of skill in buying, selling decisions underperform substantially---even relative to random selling strategies. This holds despite the similarity between the two decisions in frequency, substance and consequences for performance. Evidence suggests that an asymmetric allocation of cognitive resources such as attention can explain the discrepancy: we document a systematic, costly heuristic process when selling but not when buying.
with Leland Farmer and Allan Timmermann, Journal of Finance, April 2023
For many benchmark predictor variables, short-horizon return predictability in the U.S. stock market is local in time as short periods with significant predictability (‘pockets’) are interspersed with long periods with little or no evidence of return predictability. We document this result empirically using a flexible time-varying parameter model which estimates predictive coefficients as a nonparametric function of time and explore possible explanations of this finding, including time-varying risk-premia for which we only find limited support. Conversely, pockets of return predictability are consistent with a sticky expectations model in which investors only slowly update their beliefs about a persistent component in the cash flow process.
Note: A minor coding error impacted some of the results using the original method in the paper. In this note, we show that a simple adjustment to the estimation procedure restores the key results of the published paper.
with Joel Flynn and Alexis Toda, Theoretical Economics, January 2023
We study a general class of consumption-savings problems with recursive preferences. We characterize the sign of the consumption response to arbitrary shocks in terms of the product of two sufficient statistics: the elasticity of intertemporal substitution between contemporaneous consumption and continuation utility (EIS), and the relative elasticity of the marginal value of wealth (REMV). Under homotheticity, the REMV always equals one, so the propensity of the agent to save or dissave is always signed by the relationship of the EIS with unity. We apply our results to derive comparative statics in classical problems of portfolio allocation, consumption-savings with income risk, and entrepreneurial investment. Our results suggest empirical identification strategies for both the value of the EIS and its relationship with unity.
with Dimitris Papanikolaou and Bryan Seegmiller, Explorations in Economic History, January 2023
We detail a methodology for estimating the textual similarity between two documents while accounting for the possibility that two different words can have a similar meaning. We illustrate the method's usefulness in facilitating comparisons between documents with very different formats and vocabularies by textually linking occupation task and industry output descriptions with related technologies as described in patent texts; we also examine economic applications of the resultant document similarity measures. In a final application we demonstrate that the method also works well relative to alternatives for comparing documents within the same domain by showing that pairwise textual similarity between occupations' task descriptions strongly predicts the probability that a given worker will transition from one occupation to another. Finally, we offer some suggestions on other potential uses and guidance in implementing the method.
with Dimitris Papanikolaou. Review of Asset Pricing Studies, March 2022
We analyze the supply-side disruptions associated with Covid-19 across firms and workers. To do so, we exploit differences in the ability of workers across industries to work remotely using data from the American Time Use Survey (ATUS). We find that sectors in which a higher fraction of the workforce is not able to work remotely experienced significantly greater declines in employment, significantly more reductions in expected revenue growth, worse stock market performance, and higher expected likelihood of default. In terms of individual employment outcomes, lower-paid workers, especially female workers with young children, were significantly more affected by these disruptions. Last, we combine these ex-ante heterogeneous industry exposures with daily financial market data to create a stock return portfolio that most closely replicates the supply-side disruptions resulting from the pandemic.
Click here for additional data and resources related to the paper
with Emily Gallagher, Allan Timmermann, and Russ Wermers, Review of Financial Studies, April 2020
We study investor redemptions and portfolio rebalancing decisions of prime money market mutual funds (MMFs) during the Eurozone crisis. We find evidence that investors selectively acquire and act upon information about MMFs' risk exposures. In turn, this provides strong incentives for managers to withdraw funding from issuers whose debt becomes information-sensitive. Consistent with this, we show that MMF managers, particularly those serving the most sophisticated investors, selectively adjust their portfolio risk exposures to avoid information-sensitive European risks, while maintaining or increasing risk exposures to other regions. This mechanism helps to explain the occurrence of selective dry-ups in debt markets where delegation is common and returns to information production are often low.
with Allan Timmermann and Russ Wermers, American Economic Review, September 2016
We study daily money market mutual fund flows at the individual share class level during September 2008. This fine granularity of data facilitates new insights into investor and portfolio holding characteristics conducive to run risk in cash-like asset pools. Empirically, we find that cross-sectional flow data observed during the week of the Lehman failure are consistent with key implications of a simple model of coordination with incomplete information and strategic complementarities. Similar conclusions follow from daily models fitted to capture dynamic interactions between investors with differing levels of sophistication within the same money fund, holding constant the underlying portfolio.
with Brendan Beare, Journal of Applied Econometrics, March 2016
A large class of asset pricing models predicts that securities which have high payoffs when market returns are low tend to be more valuable than those with high payoffs when market returns are high. More generally, we expect the projection of the stochastic discount factor on the market portfolio--that is, the discounted pricing kernel evaluated at the market portfolio--to be a monotonically decreasing function of the market portfolio. Numerous recent empirical studies appear to contradict this prediction. The nonmonotonicity of empirical pricing kernel estimates has become known as the pricing kernel puzzle. In this paper we propose and apply a formal statistical test of pricing kernel monotonicity. We apply the test using seventeen years of data from the market for European put and call options written on the S&P 500 index. Statistically significant violations of pricing kernel monotonicity occur in a substantial proportion of months, suggesting that observed nonmonotonicities are unlikely to be the product of statistical noise.
Journal of Mathematical Economics, January 2012
The Shapley-Folkman Theorem places a scalar upper bound on the distance between a sum of non-convex sets and its convex hull. We observe that some information is lost when a vector is converted to a scalar to generate this bound and propose a simple normalization of the underlying space which removes this loss of information. As an example, we apply this result to the Anderson (1978) core convergence theorem, and demonstrate how our normalization leads to an intuitive, unitless upper bound on the discrepancy between an arbitrary core allocation and the corresponding competitive equilibrium allocation.
All Publications
with Klakow Akepanidtaworn, Rick Di Mascio, and Alex Imas. Journal of Finance, August 2023
Are market experts prone to heuristics, and if so, do they transfer across closely related domains---buying and selling? We investigate this question using a unique dataset of institutional investors with portfolios averaging $573 million. A striking finding emerges: while there is clear evidence of skill in buying, selling decisions underperform substantially---even relative to random selling strategies. This holds despite the similarity between the two decisions in frequency, substance and consequences for performance. Evidence suggests that an asymmetric allocation of cognitive resources such as attention can explain the discrepancy: we document a systematic, costly heuristic process when selling but not when buying.
with Leland Farmer and Allan Timmermann, Journal of Finance, April 2023
For many benchmark predictor variables, short-horizon return predictability in the U.S. stock market is local in time as short periods with significant predictability (‘pockets’) are interspersed with long periods with little or no evidence of return predictability. We document this result empirically using a flexible time-varying parameter model which estimates predictive coefficients as a nonparametric function of time and explore possible explanations of this finding, including time-varying risk-premia for which we only find limited support. Conversely, pockets of return predictability are consistent with a sticky expectations model in which investors only slowly update their beliefs about a persistent component in the cash flow process.
Note: A minor coding error impacted some of the results using the original method in the paper. In this note, we show that a simple adjustment to the estimation procedure restores the key results of the published paper.
with Joel Flynn and Alexis Toda, Theoretical Economics, January 2023
We study a general class of consumption-savings problems with recursive preferences. We characterize the sign of the consumption response to arbitrary shocks in terms of the product of two sufficient statistics: the elasticity of intertemporal substitution between contemporaneous consumption and continuation utility (EIS), and the relative elasticity of the marginal value of wealth (REMV). Under homotheticity, the REMV always equals one, so the propensity of the agent to save or dissave is always signed by the relationship of the EIS with unity. We apply our results to derive comparative statics in classical problems of portfolio allocation, consumption-savings with income risk, and entrepreneurial investment. Our results suggest empirical identification strategies for both the value of the EIS and its relationship with unity.
with Dimitris Papanikolaou and Bryan Seegmiller, Explorations in Economic History, January 2023
We detail a methodology for estimating the textual similarity between two documents while accounting for the possibility that two different words can have a similar meaning. We illustrate the method's usefulness in facilitating comparisons between documents with very different formats and vocabularies by textually linking occupation task and industry output descriptions with related technologies as described in patent texts; we also examine economic applications of the resultant document similarity measures. In a final application we demonstrate that the method also works well relative to alternatives for comparing documents within the same domain by showing that pairwise textual similarity between occupations' task descriptions strongly predicts the probability that a given worker will transition from one occupation to another. Finally, we offer some suggestions on other potential uses and guidance in implementing the method.
with Dimitris Papanikolaou. Review of Asset Pricing Studies, March 2022
We analyze the supply-side disruptions associated with Covid-19 across firms and workers. To do so, we exploit differences in the ability of workers across industries to work remotely using data from the American Time Use Survey (ATUS). We find that sectors in which a higher fraction of the workforce is not able to work remotely experienced significantly greater declines in employment, significantly more reductions in expected revenue growth, worse stock market performance, and higher expected likelihood of default. In terms of individual employment outcomes, lower-paid workers, especially female workers with young children, were significantly more affected by these disruptions. Last, we combine these ex-ante heterogeneous industry exposures with daily financial market data to create a stock return portfolio that most closely replicates the supply-side disruptions resulting from the pandemic.
Click here for additional data and resources related to the paper
with Emily Gallagher, Allan Timmermann, and Russ Wermers, Review of Financial Studies, April 2020
We study investor redemptions and portfolio rebalancing decisions of prime money market mutual funds (MMFs) during the Eurozone crisis. We find evidence that investors selectively acquire and act upon information about MMFs' risk exposures. In turn, this provides strong incentives for managers to withdraw funding from issuers whose debt becomes information-sensitive. Consistent with this, we show that MMF managers, particularly those serving the most sophisticated investors, selectively adjust their portfolio risk exposures to avoid information-sensitive European risks, while maintaining or increasing risk exposures to other regions. This mechanism helps to explain the occurrence of selective dry-ups in debt markets where delegation is common and returns to information production are often low.
with Allan Timmermann and Russ Wermers, American Economic Review, September 2016
We study daily money market mutual fund flows at the individual share class level during September 2008. This fine granularity of data facilitates new insights into investor and portfolio holding characteristics conducive to run risk in cash-like asset pools. Empirically, we find that cross-sectional flow data observed during the week of the Lehman failure are consistent with key implications of a simple model of coordination with incomplete information and strategic complementarities. Similar conclusions follow from daily models fitted to capture dynamic interactions between investors with differing levels of sophistication within the same money fund, holding constant the underlying portfolio.
with Brendan Beare, Journal of Applied Econometrics, March 2016
A large class of asset pricing models predicts that securities which have high payoffs when market returns are low tend to be more valuable than those with high payoffs when market returns are high. More generally, we expect the projection of the stochastic discount factor on the market portfolio--that is, the discounted pricing kernel evaluated at the market portfolio--to be a monotonically decreasing function of the market portfolio. Numerous recent empirical studies appear to contradict this prediction. The nonmonotonicity of empirical pricing kernel estimates has become known as the pricing kernel puzzle. In this paper we propose and apply a formal statistical test of pricing kernel monotonicity. We apply the test using seventeen years of data from the market for European put and call options written on the S&P 500 index. Statistically significant violations of pricing kernel monotonicity occur in a substantial proportion of months, suggesting that observed nonmonotonicities are unlikely to be the product of statistical noise.
Journal of Mathematical Economics, January 2012
The Shapley-Folkman Theorem places a scalar upper bound on the distance between a sum of non-convex sets and its convex hull. We observe that some information is lost when a vector is converted to a scalar to generate this bound and propose a simple normalization of the underlying space which removes this loss of information. As an example, we apply this result to the Anderson (1978) core convergence theorem, and demonstrate how our normalization leads to an intuitive, unitless upper bound on the discrepancy between an arbitrary core allocation and the corresponding competitive equilibrium allocation.